CATTANACH,
J.:—
This
is
an
appeal
from
the
assessment
of
the
appellant
under
the
Income
Tax
Act,
R.S.C.
1952,
c.
148
for
the
1955
taxation
year.
The
sole
issue
relates
to
the
appellant’s
profit
from
a
business
carried
on
by
him
under
the
name
of
W.
J.
Lawson
&
Company,
the
financial
year
of
which
ended
on
May
81,
1955.
The
question
is
whether
the
Minister
erred
in
computing
the
appellant’s
profit
for
that
year
from
trading
in
the
shares
of
a
company
called
Maneast
Uranium
Corporation
Ltd.
and
commonly
referred
to
as
‘‘Maneast’’.
In
particular
the
appellant’s
complaint
is
that
the
Minister,
in
making
that
computation,
attributed
too
high
an
amount
to
the
appellant’s
closing
inventory
of
those
shares.
In
completing
his
income
tax
return,
the
appellant
did
not
include
any
amount
in
respect
of
his
profit
from
trading
in
the
shares
in
question,
so
that
the
Minister
did
not
have
the
advantage
of
having
the
appellant’s
computation
of
his
profit
therefrom
for
the
year
when
making
the
assessment.
The
Minister
computed
the
appellant’s
profit
for
the
1955
taxation
year
from
trading
in
Maneast
shares
as
follows:
Revenue
Proceeds
from
the
sale
of
The
appellant
questions
the
accuracy
of
this
calculation
in
only
one
respect.
He
challenges
the
closing
inventory
figure
of
$213,337.50.
It
is
common
ground
that
Section
14(2)
of
the
Income
Tax
Act
requires
that
fizure
to
be
cost
or
fair
market
value,
whichever
is
the
lower.
In
the
first
place,
the
appellant
says
that,
notwithstanding
that
these
shares
were
being
traded
on
the
Toronto
Stock
Exchange
in
May
1955
at
a
high
of
73
cents
and
a
low
of
49
cents
and
in
June
1955
at
a
high
of
$1.03
cents
and
a
low
of
63
cents,
the
market
value
at
the
end
of
May
1955
was
13
cents
per
share,
being
the
value
of
the
company’s
assets
pro-rated
among
the
shares
or
the
liquidating
value,
and
that
the
closing
inventory
figure
should
therefore
have
been
computed
at
that
rate.
As
an
alternative,
the
appellant
contends
that
the
shares
should
be
valued
at
the
amount
by
which
the
total
amount
paid
by
the
appellant
for
Maneast
shares
exceeded
his
total
proceeds
from
the
sales
thereof,
which
is
$62,000,
or
approximately
11
cents
per
share.
A
third
alternative
upon
which
the
appellant
appeared
to
rely,
although
very
little
was
said
about
this
ground
in
argument,
is
that
even
if
market
value
was
higher
than
cost,
the
Minister
should
have
fixed
the
cost
of
closing
inventory,
in
accordance
with
the
specific
identification
method,
at
31
cents
per
share.
1,040,960
shares
|
$546,199.58
|
Cost
of
Sales
|
|
Opening
inventory
|
nil
|
Purchases
of
1,609,860
shares
|
$608,229.62
|
Closing
inventory
|
|
968,900
shares
at
average
|
|
cost
of
3719
|
213,337.50
|
|
394,892.12
|
Profit
from
trading
|
$151,302.46
|
I
have
no
difficulty
in
rejecting
the
appeal
insofar
as
it
rests
on
the
appellant’s
attempt
to
show
that
market
value
of
Maneast
shares
was
less
than
what
they
cost
the
appellant.
This
contention
is
based
on
the
hypothesis
that,
if
what
is
being
bought
and
sold
in
the
market
has
an
intrinsic
value
less
than
the
price
at
which
it
is
being
bought
and
sold,
the
market
value
is
the
intrinsic
value
and
not
the
amount
that
is
being
paid
in
the
market.
I
am
of
the
view
that
market
value
is
the
amount
being
paid
by
those
who
buy
and
sell
at
arm’s
length
in
the
open
market
and
that
no
evidence
was
introduced
to
establish
that
the
prices
listed
in
the
Toronto
Stock
Exchange
did
not
fairly
represent
that
price.
Evidence
that
members
of
the
general
public
were
being
incited
to
buy
the
shares
of
this
company
in
an
operation
of
gambling
at
prices
far
in
excess
of
any
sensible
valuation,
by
the
appellant’s
carefully
planned
programme
of
direct
and
indirect
publicity
and
market
operations,
does
not
make
the
amounts
paid
by
them
any
less
the
market
price
of
the
shares
that
they
were
buying.
It
may
well
be,
of
course,
that
a
few
isolated
sales
on
the
market
of
shares
in
small
quantities
can
be
shown
not
to
be
the
fair
market
value
of
a
very
large
quantity
of
shares.
Here,
however,
there
was
a
very
substantial
volume
of
sales
at
prices
greatly
in
excess
of
what
the
shares
cost
the
appellant
and
the
Toronto
Stock
Exchange
continued
to
list
Maneast
shares
at
prices
in
excess
of
cost
to
the
appellant
for
almost
a
year
after
the
end
of
the
taxation
year.
On
the
other
hand,
there
was
no
evidence
that
a
reasonable
programme
of
disposition
in
respect
of
the
appellant’s
inventory
as
of
the
end
of
May
would
have
brought
the
market
price
below
cost.
It
may
well
be
inferred
that,
if
the
appellant’s
whole
inventory
had
been
thrown
on
the
market
at
one
time,
the
price
would
have
dropped
to
nothing.
There
was
no
evidence,
however,
that
by
a
carefully
planned
programme,
he
could
not
have
disposed
of
all
the
shares
at
a
price
equal
to
or
in
excess
of
his
cost.
The
onus
was
on
the
appellant
to
show
that
the
actual
fair
market
value
of
the
inventory
at
the
end
of
May
1955
was
less
than
cost
and
in
my
opinion
the
appellant
has
failed
to
discharge
that
onus.
The
second
position
taken
by
the
appellant
is
based
on
the
evidence
of
the
accounting
witness,
Ronald
Archibald
Lachance.
In
order
to
give
full
weight
to
his
evidence,
I
quote
from
it
at
length
:
“Mr.
Burrers:
Q.
Mr.
Lachance,
you
stated
yesterday
that
vou
had
heard
the
testimony
of
Mr.
Lawson
and
I
believe
he
made
reference
to
certain
of
these
items
which
you
have
mentioned
today.
Considering
his
testimony
as
you
understood
it,
could
you
as
an
accountant
on
May
31,
1955,
have
placed
a
market
value
on
these
shares
?
A.
I
could,
I
think,
take
a
stab
at
calculating
one
of
the
definitions
of
market
value,
and
that
would
be—
His
LORDSHIP:
Market
value
or
fair
market
value?
Mr.
Butters
:
Fair
market
value,
my
lord.
Tue
Witness
:
I
don’t
know,
sir,
that
I
can
distinguish
between
market
value
and
fair
market
value,
but
I
would
say
that
I
might
take
a
stab
at
determining
the
replacement
cost,
which
is
an
accounting
element
of
market
value.
I
would
regard
Mr.
Lawson
as
a
kind
of
wholesaler,
or
at
least
he
buys
wholesale,
anyway,
because
he
at
no
time
ever
bought
any
shares
from
the
company,
treasury
stock,
at
any
more
than
one-half
of
the
quoted
market
price
at
any
time,
and
it
would
seem
reasonable
to
assume
that
his
market
value
replacement
cost
was
considerably
lower
than
the
quoted
market
price.
As
to
the
other
element
of
market,
being
realizable
value,
when
one
takes
into
consideration
the
highly
speculative
nature
of
this
whole
venture
and
the
experience—and
accountants
will
use
their
experience
in
making
judgments—the
experience
that
we
have
had
or
see
in
shares
of
speculative
stocks
dropping
very
suddenly,
I
wouldn
’t
like
to
venture
a
guess
as
to
what
the
realizable
value
of
these
shares
might
be.
I
don’t
think
anyone
could
determine
it
with
any
degree
of
accuracy.
Q.
Could
fair
market
value,
in
your
opinion,
have
been
lower
than
cost,
as
you
have
already
calculated
?
A.
It
is
possible.
Mr.
Watson:
I
think,
with
respect,
that
should
not
have
been
suggested,
my
lord.
Mr.
Butters
:
Q.
I
will
ask
the
second
question—higher
than
cost
?
A.
It
could
be
higher
or
lower,
I
wouldn’t
know.
Q.
You
don’t
know
what
the
market
value
is,
I
assume,
and
you
have
calculated
cost
on
the
FIFO
basis
for
us?
A.
Yes.
Q.
And
you
stated
that
you
have
a
choice
between
these
two
prices?
A.
Yes.
Q.
Just
what
do
you
do
as
an
accountant
when
you
are
faced
with
an
unknown
and
a
known
and
are
asked
to
compare
the
two
?
A.
I
view
this
situation
as
totally
unlike
any
normal
trading
business—hardware
or
foodstuffs,
for
instance.
The
only
situation
with
which
I
could
draw
an
analogy
would
be
that
of
a
person
who,
three
weeks
before
Christmas,
buys
1,000
Christmas
trees
for
say,
$1,000
and
starts
to
sell
them.
In
my
view
it
would
be
entirely
improper
for
him
to
say
that
he
had
made
a
$2
profit
after
selling
his
first
tree
for
$3.
He
knows
before
he
makes
any
profit
he
has
to
recover
the
$1,000
that
he
laid
out
in
the
first
place.
It
is
pretty
obvious
that
he
will
not
be
able
to
determine
his
profit
or
loss
with
accuracy
until
the
day
after
Christmas,
on
which
day
the
trees
in
his
inventory
will
be
worthless.
One
could
apply
the
same
generally
accepted
costing
techniques
that
I
described
earlier
to
this
Christmas
tree
merchant
on
any
day
during
the
three-week
period
and
come
up
with
an
apparent
profit,
but
I
don’t
believe
that
is
profit,
at
that
time
in
this
case,
because
the
results
would
not
make
good
sense,
and
it
is
my
Judgment
that
those
techniques
can’t
be
applied
in
Mr.
Lawson’s
circumstances
for
the
same
reason.
At
May
31,
1955,
Mr.
Lawson
had
some
$62,000
of
his
original
investment
tied
up
in
the
Maneast
shares.
It
would
be
my
view
that
unless
he
recovered
this
money
there
would
be
no
certainty
that
he
had
made
a
profit.
It
seems
to
me
that
in
order
to
say
that
someone
has
made
a
profit
he
must
have
made
that
profit
and
have
some
choice
as
to
how
he
is
going
to
use
it.
In
this
ease,
because
of
the
nature
of
this
venture,
as
I
understand
it,
he
was
locked
into
it
and
he
didn’t
have
any
profit
to
enjoy.
The
effect
of
this
approach
would
be
to
value
the
568,900
shares
of
Maneast
at
$62,000,
that
is
about
11
cents
a
share,
being
the
unrecovered
cost
of
the
venture
at
that
date.
Q.
Could
that
$62,000
figure
in
your
opinion
represent
the
cost
of
closing
inventory
to
Mr.
Lawson
?
A.
I
think
it
would
be
described
as
such,
although
it
is
more
like
the
cost
of
his
venture
to
date.
I
would
be
satisfied
to
call
it
the
cost
of
his
inventory
to
date.’
The
substance
of
foregoing,
as
the
witness
put
it,
is
that
he
would
value
the
568,900
shares
in
the
closing
inventory
at
$62,000
being
the
amount
by
which
the
total
cost
of
such
shares
to
the
appellant
exceeds
the
proceeds
of
sale
of
the
shares
that
the
appellant
sold
before
that
time.
The
simple
answer
to
the
opinion
of
this
witness
that
the
closing
inventory
should
be
included
at
$62,000,
if
such
opinion
is
admissible
evidence,
is
that
it
is
neither
the
fair
market
value
of
the
shares
in
the
closing
inventory,
nor
the
cost
of
the
shares
in
the
closing
inventory
and
therefore
it
cannot
be
the
correct
amount
to
use
in
respect
of
closing
inventory
under
either
Section
14(2)
of
the
Act
or
the
regulations
made
thereunder.
The
remaining
question
is
whether
the
appellant
has
shown
that
the
figure
of
$213,337.50
used
by
the
Minister
in
respect
of
the
closing
inventory
is
excessive
on
the
cost
basis.
It
would
appear
that,
if
the
cost
of
the
inventory
had
been
fixed
on
the
first
in
first
out
basis
(FIFO),
the
appropriate
figure
would
have
been
approximately
$172,000.
No
evidence
was
given,
however,
that
would
lead
to
the
conclusion
that
this
assumption
was
closer
to
reality
than
the
averaging
basis
adopted
by
the
Minister.
In
other
words,
the
evidence
as
to
which
stock
certificates
were
used
for
particular
sales
did
not
lead
to
the
conclusion
that
there
was
a
tendency
to
use
the
oldest
certificates
first.
That
being
so,
there
is
no
balance
of
probability
in
favour
of
the
view
that
the
certificates
on
hand
at
the
end
of
May,
1955
actually
cost
$172,000
rather
than
the
amount
placed
on
them
by
the
Minister
on
the
averaging
basis
and
the
onus
of
proof
to
show
that
the
Minister
was
wrong
was
on
the
appellant.
With
regard
to
costing
on
the
specific
identification
basis,
I
have
been
unable
to
satisfy
myself
that
this
was
worked
out
on
the
evidence.
In
argument,
counsel
for
the
appellant
says:
“The
specific
identification
of
the
shares
on
hand
at
the
year-end
worked
out
to
31
cents
on
an
acquisition
cost
basis.
I
think
Mr.
Newton
agreed
that,
assuming
the
specific
identification
which
appears
from
Exhibits
8
and
10,
the
assumption
on
his
calculations
would
not
be
appropriate,
and
following
ing
the
actual
known
fact
we
come
up
with
31
cents.’’
A
review
of
the
evidence,
and
in
particular
that
of
Mr.
Newton,
does
not
show
that
it
was
established
that
certain
stock
certificates
on
hand
at
the
brokers
on
May
31,
1955,
representing
568,900
shares,
belonged
to
the
appellant
and
cost
him
an
average
of
31
cents
per
share.
While
a
large
proportion
of
such
shares
can
be
traced
on
the
evidence,
there
remains
over
40,000
shares
which
cannot
be
specifically
identified
and
the
cost
thereof
would
have
to
be
fixed
on
one
of
the
assumptions.
The
evidence
is
not
sufficiently
precise
to
enable
me
to
cost
the
closing
inventory
on
the
specific
identification
basis
and,
therefore,
I
do
not
come
to
any
conclusion
as
to
whether
it
is
appropriate
in
the
circumstances.
Accordingly,
I
am
left
with
the
Minister’s
assessment
and
I
would
dismiss
the
appeal
were
it
not
for
the
submission
made
by
counsel
for
the
Minister
that
the
proper
figure
for
valuing
the
appellant’s
closing
inventory
is
34.1
cents
per
share
instead
of
37.5
cents
per
share,
because
of
averaging
over
a
lesser
period
than
the
entire
fiscal
year.
As
this
is
favourable
ot
the
taxpayer,
I
accept
that
submission
and
judgment
will
therefore
go
that
the
appeal
is
allowed
and
the
assessment
is
to
be
varied
as
indicated.
As
the
appellant
is
unsuccessful
on
the
issues
that
occupied
the
most
of
the
time
at
trial
there
will
be
no
costs.
Judgment
accordingly.