Gibson,
J.:—This
is
an
appeal
from
the
decision
of
the
Tax
Appeal
Board
as
to
the
appellant’s
1962
income
tax
assessment
wherein
the
excess
of
receipts
over
outlay
realized
on
a
first
mortgage
purchased
in
1957
and
redeemed
and
paid
off
in
1962
was
found
to
be
income
and
not
a
capital
gain.
The
appellant
in
his
formal
Notice
of
Appeal
puts
his
grounds
for
appeal
in
this
way:
A.
STATEMENT
OF
FACTS
In
the
month
of
July,
1957,
the
taxpayer
in
association
with
a
client
bought
through
another
solicitor
a
first
mortgage
on
the
property
known
as
90
Campbell
Avenue,
Toronto,
Ontario.
The
amount
then
owing
on
the
mortgage
was
Eight
thousand
five
hundred
dollars
($8,500.00)
for
principal
with
interest
at
the
rate
of
six
and
one-half
per
cent
(6^%)
per
annum
from
the
5th
July,
1957.
The
taxpayer
and
his
client
paid
the
sum
of
Seven
thousand
one
hundred
dollars
($7,100.00)
with
each
of
them
putting
up
one-
half
of
the
purchase
price.
The
source
of
the
taxpayer’s
share
of
the
funds
used
for
the
purpose
of
acquiring
the
mortgage
was
his
personal
savings.
The
mortgage
was
paid
off
in
full
in
July,
1962.
B.
REASONS
THAT
THE
TAXPAYER
INTENDS
TO
SUBMIT:
Any
and
all
profits
(apart
from
the
interest
provided
for
in
the
mortgage)
which
were
received
by
the
taxpayer
during
the
year
1962
from
the
investment
made
by
him
in
this
mortgage
were
not
profits
from
a
business
carried
on
by
the
taxpayer
during
the
said
year
within
the
meaning
of
Sections
3,
4
and
139(1)
(e)
of
the
Income
Tax
Act,
were
not
in
satisfaction
of
interest
within
the
meaning
of
Section
6(1)
(b)
of
the
Act,
and
were
not
income
from
property
within
the
meaning
of
Sections
3
and
4
of
the
Act,
but
were
the
realization
by
the
taxpayer
of
a
capital
accretion
on
a
mortgage
investment
made
by
him.*
The
respondent
submits
that
the
difference*
between
the
amount
advanced
by
the
appellant
on
the
security
of
the
said
mortgage
and
the
amount
received
by
him
upon
its
subsequent
redemption
during
the
appellant’s
1962
tax
year
is
a
profit
from
a
‘‘business’’
carried
on
by
the
appellant
during
the
said
year
and
is
income
within
the
meaning
of
Sections
3,
4
and
paragraph
(e)
of
subsection
(1)
of
Section
139
of
the
Income
Tax
Act;
or,
in
the
alternative,
that
this
amount
was
an
amount
received
by
the
appellant
during
his
1962
taxation
year
as
interest
or
on
account
or
in
lieu
of
payment
of
or
in
satisfaction
of
interest
and,
therefore,
is
income
from
property
within
the
meaning
of
Sections
8,
4
and
paragraph
(b)
of
subsection
(1)
Section
6
of
the
Income
Tax
Act.
The
relevant
facts
in
this
matter
briefly
are
as
follows:
The
appellant
between
1956
and
1963
acquired
thirteen
(13)
mortgages,
eleven
(11)
of
which
were
so-called
bonus
or
discount
mortgages,
six
(6)
of
which
were
second
mortgages,
and
seven
(7)
of
which
were
first
mortgages.
The
appellant’s
law
office,
in
which
there
were
two
other
partners,
as
part
of
its
solicitor
practice
at
the
time
of
the
hearing,
managed
the
collection
for
clients
of
mortgages
which
had
an
aggregate
principal
value
of
over
four
and
a
half
million
dollars.
In
1957
it
was
not
that
much
but
still
the
aggregate
principal
value
of
the
mortgages
then
managed
was
substantial.
The
appellant
acquired
these
mortgages
for
his
personal
account
during
the
period
when
he
was
carrying
on
his
practice
and
all
of
them
came
to
his
attention
by
reason
of
the
fact
that
he
was
practising
law
as
a
general
practitioner
and
the
fact
that
part
of
his
practice
consisted
of
mortgage
transactions.
in
computing
his
profit)
as
interest
or
on
account
or
in
lieu
of
payment
of,
or
in
satisfaction
of
interest;
139.
(1)
In
this
Act,
(e)
“business”
includes
a
profession,
calling,
trade,
manufacture
or
undertaking
of
any
kind
whatsoever
and
includes
an
adventure
or
concern
in
the
nature
of
trade
but
does
not
include
an
office
or
employment;
The
mortgages
acquired
for
his
personal
account
are
not
large
in
number
;
and
the
evidence
is
that
the
appellant
also
purchased
some
stocks
and
bonds
for
his
personal
account
during
this
same
period
of
time.
The
purchase
of
these
mortgages
and
the
stocks
and
bonds
were
made
from
savings
of
the
appellant
and
such
purchases
in
total
were
not
substantial.
The
specific
mortgage,
the
gain
on
which
is
the
subject
of
this
appeal,
was
on
the
premises
known
as
90
Campbell
Avenue,
Toronto,
The
circumstances
surrounding
its
acquisition
were
as
follows:
One
Williams,
who
was
described
as
a
speculator,
purchased
90
Campbell
Avenue,
Toronto,
on
June
11,
1957
for
$10,000.
In
July
1957
he
sold
these
premises
to
one
Lawrence
for
$13,700.
Lawrence
paid
Williams
$2,200
cash
and
gave
him
back
a
first
mortgage
and
second
mortgage
in
the
respective
sums
of
$8,500
and
$3,000.
These
mortgages
were
drawn
obviously
for
the
purpose
of
immediate
resale.
The
first
mortgage
of
$8,500
was
then
purchased
by
the
appellant
and
a
client
in
July
1957
for
$7,100
(and
therefore
at
a
discount
of
$1,400
from
its
face
value).
This
mortgage
bore
interest
at
614%
P
annum
on
its
face
value
of
$8,500
and
was
paid
off
in
1962.
This
subject
mortgage,
and
all
of
the
mortgages
acquired
by
the
appellant
according
to
his
evidence
were
purchased
by
the
appellant
after
he
had
inspected
each
proposed
mortgaged
premises
and
had
made
a
decision
that
each
purchase
was
a
safe
investment
for
him.
It
is
the
gain
of
the
appellant
resulting
from
the
acquisition
of
this
mortgage
at
a
discount
and
the
holding
of
it
until
it
was
paid
off
at
face
value
that
is
the
subject
matter
of
this
appeal.
As
a
perusal
of
the
cases
shows,
it
is
often
difficult
to
determine
the
exact
nature
of
a
receipt,
whether
income
or
capital
gain.
This
is
especially
true
when
a
distinction
is
sometimes
made
between
the
gain
realized
from
the
acquisition
and
holding
to
maturity
of
a
discount
mortgage,
such
as
the
subject
mortgage
in
this
case,
and
the
gain
realized
from
the
acquisition
of
and
holding
to
maturity
of
so-called
‘
discount
bonds’’.
To
assist
in
the
determination
of
whether
a
gain
is
one
of
capital
or
income
in
my
view,
it
is
helpful
to
consider
the
economist’s
conception
of
the
nature
of
capital
gains
and
the
relation
of
these
gains
to
ordinary
income.
Before
mentioning
such
economist’s
concepts,
as
I
understand
them,
however,
it
should
be
noted
that
the
nature
of
the
gain
from
“discounts”,
that
is
the
face
value
less
the
amount
ad-
vanced
or
paid,
received
under
mortgage
contracts
have
been
the
subject
of
many
judicial
decisions.
In
James
Frederick
Scott
v.
M.N.R.,
[1968]
S.C.R.
228;
[1963]
C.T.C.
176,
Judson,
J.
reviewed
the
two
kinds
of
results
of
such
cases
in
which
the
issue
in
each
was
resolved
by
deciding
whether
or
not
the
taxpayer
was
in
a
‘‘business’’
within
the
meaning
of
Section
139
(1)(e)
of
the
Act,
and
said
at
pp.
225,
177:
This
diversity
of
opinion
is
understandable
when
the
decision
must
depend
upon
a
full
review
of
the
facts
in
each
case
for
the
purpose
of
determining
whether
the
discounts
can
be
classified
as
income
from
a
business.
Even
on
the
same
facts,
there
is
room
for
disagreement
among
judges
on
the
conclusions
that
should
be
drawn
from
these
activities
of
a
taxpayer,
for
the
Act
nowhere
specifically
deals
with
these
discounts,
as
it
does,
for
example,
in
Section
105(a)
with
shares
redeemed
or
acquired
by
a
corporation
at
a
premium.
It
is
possible
to
deal
expressly
with
the
problem
and
the
Act
has
not
done
so.
and
concluded
in
that
case
(pp.
228,
180)
that
the
taxpayer
was
in
.
.
.
the
highly
speculative
business
of
purchasing
these
obligations
at
a
discount
and
holding
them
to
maturity
in
order
to
realize
the
maximum
amount
of
profit
out
of
the
transactions,
and
that
the
profits
are
taxable
income
and
not
a
capital
gain.
And
it
should
also
be
noted
that
such
‘‘discounts’’
received
under
mortgage
contracts
have
been
also
the
subject
of
consideration
in
many
cases
as
to
whether
they
were
“interest”
within
the
meaning
of
Section
6(1)
(b)
of
the
Act.
As
to
the
latter,
it
may
be
that
the
Parliament
of
Canada
when
it
referred
to
‘‘interest’’
in
Section
6(1)
(b)
of
the
Income
Tax
Act
had
in
mind
the
same
meaning
of
the
word
as
in
the
Interest
Act,
R.S.C.
1952,
ce.
156.
If
that
is
so,
there
may
be
serious
doubt
that
such
‘‘discounts’’
are
‘‘interest’’
within
the
meaning
of
Section
6(1)
(b)
because
of
the
decision
of
the
Supreme
Court
of
Canada
in
Attorney-General
for
Ontario
v.
Barfried
Enterprises
Limited,
[1963]
S.C.R.
570.*
In
my
view
the
Court
when
it
referred
in
that
case
to
‘‘discounts’’
as
synonymous
with
“interest”
under
the
Interest
Act
was
referring
to
the
gain
from
the
type
of
discounts
arising
in
Canadian
financial
markets
from
such
sources
as
(1)
Canada
Treasury
Bills
sold
by
the
Government
of
Canada
every
Thursday
at
a
discount
and
maturing
at
par;
(2)
the
loans
made
by
way
of
the
purchase
of
non-interest
bearing
post-dated
Bankers’
Acceptances
of
Canadian
Chartered
Banks;*
and
(3)
the
mechanical
application
by
Canadian
Chartered
Banks
of
their
‘‘call
loan”
or
collateral
security
loan
business.
“Discounts”
from
such
sources
not
only
are
all
‘‘interest’’
within
the
meaning
of
the
Interest
Act
but
are
also
all
“income”
within
the
meaning
of
the
Income
Tax
Act,
being
income
from
a
“source”
within
the
meaning
of
the
opening
words
of
Section
3
of
the
Income
Tax
Act
and
also
specifically
‘‘interest’’
within
the
meaning
of
Section
6(1)
(b)
of
the
Income
Tax
Act.
Preliminary
also
to
recording
the
reasons
for
the
decision
in
this
case,
I
mention
that
I
would
have
no
difficulty
in
finding
that
the
gain
arising
out
of
this
discount
mortgage
transaction
was
income,
being
profit
from
a
‘‘business’’
within
the
meaning
of
Section
139(1)(e)
of
the
Act
but
do
not
choose
to
do
so;
and
for
the
reasons
just
stated,
I
do
not
wish
to
say
whether
the
discount
from
this
particular
mortgage
was
‘‘interest’’
within
the
meaning
of
Section
6(1)
(b)
of
the
Act.
I
prefer
instead,
to
found
my
decision
in
this
case
by
resolving
the
question
of
whether
or
not
this
gain
was
income
from
a
‘‘source’’
within
the
meaning
of
the
opening
words
of
Section
3
of
the
Income
Tax
Act.
And
as
far
as
I
know,
there
is
no
decision
of
this
Court
or
of
the
Supreme
Court
of
Canada
in
which
a
question
of
this
kind
has
been
resolved
by
deciding
that
such
a
discount
was
income
from
a
‘‘source’’
within
the
meaning
of
the
opening
words
of
Section
3
of
the
Act,
without
deciding
whether
it
was
income
from
any
of
the
particular
sources
detailed
in
Section
3
or
elsewhere
in
the
Act.
In
considering
income
from
a
‘‘source”’
that
falls
outside
the
statutory
definition
of
‘‘business’’
(as
was
said
by
Noël,
J.
in
George
H.
Steer
v.
M.N.R.,
[1965]
2
Ex.
C.R.
458;
[1965]
C.T.C.
181)
it
should
be
noted
that
it
is
‘‘.
.
.
not
merely
the
aggregation
of
one’s
incomes
from
all
sources
from
which
there
were
incomes
in
the
year
but
it
is
made
up
of
the
gains
from
all
sources
minus
the
losses
from
these
sources
or,
expressed
otherwise,
the
net
income
from
all
sources
of
income
taken
together.’’
In
other
words,
in
determining
such
income
for
the
purpose
of
the
Income
Tax
Act
as
was
held
in
that
case,
there
must
be
allowed
‘‘.
.
.
the
deduction
of
any
outlay
or
expense
involved
in
earning
income
from
a
‘source’
that
falls
outside
the
classes
of
sources
of
income
specifically
named
in
Section
3
(i.e.,
businesses,
property,
and
offices
or
employments),
..
.’’.
Relating
this
to
the
economist’s
concepts,
and
beginning
the
consideration
of
such
concepts
as
I
understand
them,
relevant
to
this
matter,
it
should
first
be
noted
that
when
economists
speak
of
‘‘income’’,
they
refer
to
‘‘net
income’’
in
the
same
sense
as
it
is
used
in
that
case.
All
proper
charges
therefore
must
first
be
deducted,
which
in
the
case
of
acquisition
of
securities
would
include
commissions
paid,
legal
fees
and
so
forth.
Secondly,
as
I
understand
the
matter,
the
conceptional
distinction
made
by
economists
between
capital
gains
and
income
is
as
follows.*
An
economist
when
he
speaks
of
‘‘money
income’’
is
talking
about
what
he
refers
to
as
‘‘social
income’’.+
And
the
interest
portion
of
‘‘money
income”
the
economist
says
includes
three
items,
namely
(1)
pure
interest,
(2)
risk,
and
(3)
liquidity.
Pure
interest
is
the
price
paid
for
waiting.
Risk
is
the
cause
of
the
reward
which
exists
because
there
is
a
possibility
of
there
being
a
loss
of
the
capital
advanced.
Liquidity
is
self-explanatory
and
includes
the
range,
market
and
time
of
availability
of
potential
purchasers
for
the
particular
security
contract.
The
economist
considers
that
pure
interest,
risk,
and
liquidity
of
a
security
are
always
respectively
reflected
in
yield
;
and
that
in
speaking
of
yield,
as
opposed
to
contractual
interest
rate,
he
means
the
net
result
having
regard
to
such
interest
rate
and
the
price
of
the
security.
Yield,
therefore,
in
his
view,
takes
into
consideration
any-discount
or
premium
involved
in
the
price
of
any
security.
Thirdly,
one
other
qualifying
factor
the
economist
says,
must
be
introduced
and
that
is
that
there
must
exist
a
perfect
market
or,
in
other
words,
that
there
must
be
no
uncertainties.
Under
such
conditions,
that
is
an
absolute
guarantee
of
perfect
market
conditions,
the
market
capitalization
of
assets
according
to
the
economist
would
equal
their
present
discount
value.
In
other
words,
anyone
could
borrow
or
lend
as
much
as
he
wished
at
a
single
competitive
market
rate
of
interest.
Every
asset
would
be
yielding
the
same
market
rate
of
interest.
This
equality
of
yield
would
result
from
the
way
competitors
bid
up
or
bid
down
the
market
price
of
any
asset—whether
it
be
a
bond,
a
stock,
a
mortgage,
a
patent,
a
going
business,
a
piece
of
real
estate,
or
any
earning
stream
of
other
income
whatsoever.
Because,
however,
there
is
no
perfect
competition
and
there
are
no
certainties,
the
economist
recognizes
that
there
do
result
in
certain
circumstances
capital
gains
or
losses.
They
are
bred
by
uncertainty
and
they
cannot
be
predictably
expected
to
occur
again
and
again.
The
perfect
competition
or
condition
of
absolute
certainty
that
the
economist
speaks
of
means
the
situation
that
would
obtain
if
each
seller
had
absolutely
no
control
over
price;
in
other
words,
it
means
that
each
seller’s
demand
curve
is
perfectly
horizontal
and
infinitely
elastic;
it
means
that
no
person
is
able
to
control
any
significant
fraction
of
the
total
of
any
category
of
productive
resources.
But
in
the
individual
case
histories
of
many
of
these
so-called
capital
gains
or
losses,
among
economists
there
will
be
wide
divergence
of
opinion
as
to
whether
the
“gain”
or
‘‘loss’’
was
an
income
receipt
or
loss
or
a
true
capital
gain
or
loss.
The
origins
of
substantially
all
capital
gains
are
not,
however,
the
subject
of
diversified
opinions.
Capital
gains
in
the
main
arise
from
capital
assets.
Buying
and
selling
such
income
producing
rights
as
corporate
securities,
real
estate,
leases
and
contracts
and
disposing
of
these
assets
at
prices
higher
than
the
original
cost
produce
gains
which
are
not
related
to
the
income
flows
associated
with
these
assets.
Capital
gains
from
increases
in
land
values,
from
investment
in
the
stock
market
and
from
the
creation
and
expansion
of
industrial
empires
are
the
most
well
known
sources
of
such
capital
gains.
The
unexpected
nature
of
a
capital
gain
is
the
main
thing
that
most
economists
stress
in
expressing
the
conceptual
difference
between
capital
gains
and
ordinary
income.*
In
other
words,
they
say
that
the
expected
rise
in
the
value
of
an
asset
is
ordinary
income
and
an
unexpected
rise
in
value
is
a
capital
gain.
Therefore,
in
this
view,
pure
capital
gains
are
windfall
additions
on
one’s
assets
or,
as
put
by
Seltzer,
‘
Unforeseen
increases
in
the
real
value
of
a
man’s
existing
property
not
directly
attributable
to
his
efforts,
intelligence,
capital
or
risk-taking.’’*
The
main
kinds
of
changes
which
affect
the
value
of
assets
which
give
rise
to
capital
gains
may
be
grouped
into
three
general
types:
Changes
in
expectations
regarding
the
net
receipts
to
be
obtained
from
a
capital
asset,
unexpected
changes
in
interest
rates,
and
changes
in
the
disposition
of
investors
to
face
uncertainties.
As
previously
mentioned,
in
a
situation
of
perfect
competition
the
present
value
of
a
capital
asset
is
based
on
the
discount
value
of
the
expected
flow
of
receipts
of
the
asset
over
its
life;
and
because
there
is
no
such
thing
as
perfect
competition
and
there
is
no
such
thing
as
certainty,
any
potential
investor
must
estimate
these
receipts
and
discount
them
having
regard
to
the
basis
of
his
experience
and
knowledge
of
the
present
which
inevitably
yields
unstable
results.!
The
investors’
estimates
of
future
yields
are
therefore
in
practice
forever
changing
for
a
variety
of
reasons,
many
of
which
are
subjective.
As
a
result,
capital
gains
in
a
pure
sense
do
arise,
according
to
the
economist,
from
unanticipated
changes
in
the
value
of
capital
assets.
This
is
because,
putting
it
in
other
words,
this
latter
value
is
obtained
by
discounting
the
expected
stream
of
income
of
an
asset
over
its
life,
and
unexpected
changes
in
the
stream
or
in
the
discounting
factors
will
affect
the
capitalized
value.
These,
as
I
understand
them,
are
the
economic
origins
of
capital
gains.
Again
they
differ
from
ordinary
income
only
by
virtue
of
their
unexpected
character.
In
law,
however,
the
meaning
of
capital
gain
is
not
as
refined
and
narrow
as
the
economist’s
concept.
In
law,
as
the
cases
indicate,
a
capital
gain
is
not
always
completely
unanticipated
and
it
is
often
a
mixture
of
the
other
types
of
factor
returns—wages,
rents,
interest
and
profits.
Relating
these
concepts
to
the
matter
in
issue,
it
should
first
be
noted
that
a
market
condition
which
approaches
in
some
degree
perfect
competition
and
approaches
absolute
certainty,
does
exist
in
the
sale
of
certain
securities
through
recognized
stock
exchanges
and
other
traditional
financial
markets.
The
business
community
recognizes
that
in
respect
to
securities
which
are
traded
on
such
recognized
stock
exchanges
or
in
such
other
traditional
financial
markets,
that
there
will
be
from
time
to
time
fortuitous
gains
which
the
business
community
categorizes
as
capital
gains
and
not
as
income
receipts.
The
business
community
explains
that
these
gains
happen
because
the
market
does
not
always
reflect
the
true
worth
of
such
securities
and
therefore
such
gains
are
expressed
in
the
form
of
capital.
It
is
this
type
of
capital
gain
that
the
English
Court
of
Appeal
in
Lomax
(H.M.
Inspector
of
Taxes)
v.
Peter
Dixon
and
Son,
Limited,
[1948]
1
K.B.
671,
discussed.
Its
relevance
to
the
Canadian
market,
as
I
understand
it,
briefly
is
as
follows:
In
Canada
about
1958
there
developed
a
money
market
for
so-called
discount
bonds.
This
became
especially
pronounced
after
a
very
substantial
market
break
in
the
fall
of
1959.
The
money
market
for
these
discount
bonds,
in
the
main,
was
utilized
by
corporate
investors
who
had
idle
surplus
funds
for
temporary
investment.
The
Government
of
Canada,
for
example,
in
March
of
1959
sold
a
214%
issue
due
in
thirteen
months
at
$97.90
to
yield
4.6%.
This
issue,
in
the
main,
as
stated,
was
purchased
by
such
corporate
investors
and
such
corporate
investors
treated
the
gain
arising
from
this
discount
to
maturity
or
the
difference
between
the
buying
and
selling
price
if
sold
prior
to
maturity
as
a
capital
gain
or
at
least
non-taxable
income
and
paid
corporate
tax
on
the
interest
or
coupon
only.
Provincial
governments
in
Canada,
also
about
this
time,
began
to
issue
bonds
at
a
discount.
They
also
looked,
in
the
main,
for
corporate
investors
who
considered
these
bonds
to
afford
a
high
degree
of
safety
of
principal
and
interest
and
a
high
degree
of
liquidity.
(Compare
the
economists’
Concept
of
money
income
above
mentioned.
)
Between
early
1958
and
December,
1960
the
Canadian
Provinces
and
their
authorities
raised
millions
of
dollars
through
the
sale
of
discount
bonds
or
notes
with
terms
ranging
from
six
months
to
two
or
three
years.
In
the
vast
majority
of
cases
a
2%
coupons
was
used
and
the
gross
yield
ranged
from
2.40%
to
5.65%.
Then
finally,
in
December,
1960
a
three
million
dollar
issue
was
done
by
a
province.
This
issue
was
in
two
parts
and
each
bore
a
2%
coupons.
One
part
had
a
ten
year
term
and
was
priced
at
$76.28
to
yield
5.05%.
The
other
was
a
fifteen
year
term
and
was
priced
at
$66.95
to
yield
5.20%.
This
led
the
Government
of
Canada
to
enacting
Section
7
(2)
of
the
Income
Tax
Act.*
This
section
then
provided
(and
now
provides)
that
for
any
new
bonds
issued
where
the
coupon
rate
was
less
than
5
%
the
gross
or
total
yield
on
which
the
bond
could
be
sold
could
not
exceed
the
coupon
by
more
than
/3.
If
this
gross
yield
exceeded
the
coupon
by
more
than
14,
then
the
whole
of
the
discount
would
be
deemed
to
be
income
in
the
hands
of
the
first
Canadian
resident
taxable
holder
of
the
instrument.
This
meant,
for
example,
to
avoid
the
income
tax
implication
of
Section
7(2)
for
a
bond
bearing
a
fixed
or
coupon
rate
of
2%
the
highest
gross
rate
at
which
it
could
now
be
sold
was
2.66%.
The
enactment
of
Section
7(2)
of
the
Income
Tax
Act
therefore
brought
an
end
to
the
issuance
of
these
‘‘deep
discount’’
bonds.
But
the
issuance
and
sale
of
securities
to
taxable
corporations
for
investing
of
surplus
funds
has
continued.
All
these
new
issues
have
been
and
are
now
tailored
to
comply
with
the
‘‘coupon
plus
14’’
requirements
of
Section
7(2)
of
the
Income
Tax
Act,
that
is
they
provide
an
effective
yield
to
maturity
or
to
the
earliest
call
date
that
does
not
exceed
the
contractual
rate
by
more
than
one-third.
Corporate
investors
who
buy
these
securities
and
hold
them,
apparently
treat
the
gain
arising
as
a
capital
gain
on
the
basis
that
they
are
investing
temporary
surplus
funds
and
are
not
in
a
‘‘business’’
within
the
meaning
of
Section
139(1)
(e)
of
the
Act.*
So
much
for
the
discussion
of
discount
bonds.
Reverting
now
to
the
subject
matter
in
this
case,
it
is
clear
that
no
such
similar
market
situation
obtains
in
the
case
of
the
mortgage
in
this
action.
As
stated,
this
was
a
first
mortgage
purchased
at
a
discount
and
it
did
not
come
into
existence
in
a
market
which
in
any
way
approached
a
situation
of
perfect
competition.
Instead,
this
mortgage
was
tailor-made
by
the
parties
and
no
free
forces
of
the
market
obtained
which
caused
this
discount
to
arise.
(There
may
be
cases
in
respect
of
mortgage
discounts
where
the
concept
of
the
decision
in
the
Lomax
case
(supra)
may
apply
but
these
would
be
exceptions
in
my
view,
especially
in
the
light
of
the
knowledge
of
how
the
usual
type
of
mortgage
contract
is
entered
into
in
this
country.)
The
yield
to
the
appellant
on
this
mortgage
amounted
to
11.18%.
The
gain
on
this
particular
mortgage,
I
am
of
the
opinion
that
no
economist
would
categorize
as
a
capital
gain.
Every
economist
would
say
that
there
was
not
perfect
competition
in
the
market
when
this
mortgage
contract
was
entered
into
and
sold,
that
there
was
substantial
control
over
the
market
by
the
per-
sons
concerned,
that
there
was
nothing
fortuitous,
unsought,
uncalculated
and
unexpected
about
this
gain,
and
that
therefore
the
receipt
was
all
income.
In
my
view
the
appellant
entered
into
perfectly
normal
transactions
with
one
purpose
in
mind
when
he
purchased
this
mortgage,
the
other
mortgages,
and
the
stocks
and
bonds
during
the
relevant
period.
‘‘He
put
to
work’’
his
excess
fees
from
his
earnings
from
the
practice
of
law
so
that
he
might
have
what
is
called
a
‘‘second
income”
by
various
stock
brokerage
houses
and
other
persons
who
sell
securities
in
the
various
financial
markets
today.
This
second
income”
from
this
subject
mortgage
transaction
was
identical
with
and
was
income
as
meant
in
the
Income
Tax
Act.
In
the
result,
therefore,
I
am
of
opinion
and
found
my
decision
on
the
grounds
that
the
profit
from
this
transaction
was
income
from
a
“source”
within
the
meaning
of
the
opening
words
of
Section
3
of
the
Income
Tax
Act
as
judicially
considered
by
Noel,
J.
in
George
H.
Steer
v.
M.N.R.
(supra),
whether
or
not
it
was
profit
from
a
‘‘business’’
within
the
meaning
of
Section
139(1)
(e)
of
the
Income
Tax
Act,
or
‘‘interest’’
within
the
meaning
of
Section
6(1)
(b)
of
the
Income
Tax
Act.
In
doing
so,
I
am
adopting
for
this
purpose
the
economist’s
concept
of
income
as
described
above.
Accordingly,
the
appeal
is
dismissed
with
costs,
and
the
matter
is
referred
back
for
re-assessment,
not
inconsistent
with
these
reasons,
for
the
purpose
of
deducting
all
proper
charges
and
thereby
correctly
computing
the
net
income
received
by
the
appellant
from
his
mortgage
transaction.