Guy
Tremblay:—These
appeals
were
heard
on
common
evidence
in
Vancouver,
British
Columbia,
on
August
9
and
10,
1982.
1.
The
Point
at
Issue
The
point
at
issue
is
the
V-Day
value
of
pieces
of
land
located
at
Duncan,
BC.
They
were
sold
for
$825,000
on
August
31,
1976.
The
appellants’
contention
is
that
the
V-Day
value
was
$419,000
because
of
the
theory
of
the
special
purchaser.
The
respondent
contends
that
the
V-Day
value
of
the
said
property
is
$250,000.
There
is
also
another
point
concerning
the
recapture
of
capital
cost
allowance.
2.
The
Burden
of
Proof
2.01
The
burden
is
on
the
appellants
to
show
that
the
respondent’s
assessments
are
incorrect.
This
burden
of
proof
results
especially
from
several
judicial
decisions,
including
the
judgment
delivered
by
the
Supreme
Court
of
Canada
in
Johnston
v
MNR,
[1948]
CTC
195;
3
DTC
1182.
3.
The
Facts
3.01
The
appellants
are
companies
duly
incorporated
under
the
laws
of
British
Columbia.
3.02
On
August
31,
1976,
the
appellants
sold
the
following
property
to
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada,
located
at
Duncan,
BC,
for
$825,000
including
the
buildings:
(a)
lots
12
and
13
owned
by
Lakehouse
Enterprises
Ltd;
(b)
lots
1,10
and
the
remainder
of
14
owned
by
Lakehouse
Holdings
Ltd.
3.03
On
December
31,
1971,
Lakehouse
Enterprises
Ltd
only
owned
lot
13.
It
had
been
purchased
in
1968.
Lot
12
was
acquired
in
November
1972
for
$51,963
including
land
and
buildings.
In
1974,
on
the
said
lot
12,
a
building
of
1,120
square
feet
was
built
as
an
extension
of
the
existing
buildings.
3.04
On
December
31,
1971,
Lakehouse
Holdings
Ltd
owned
only
lots
1
and
14.
They
had
been
purchased
respectively
in
1955
and
1957.
Lot
10
was
purchased
in
November
1973
for
$27,500.
3.05
Lakehouse
Holdings
Ltd
and
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada
had
entered
into
a
15-year
lease
commencing
July
15,
1969
with
option
to
renew
for
two
10-year
terms.
The
annual
rental
was
$23,000
with
monthly
payments
of
$1,916.97
payable
in
advance.
3.06
After
the
evidence
given
by
different
witnesses,
especially
the
appraisers,
(5
appraisal
reports
were
filed)
the
parties
agreed
that
the
normal
price
of
the
subject
property
(lots
1,
13
and
14)
was
$250,000
on
December
31,
1971.
3.07
The
appellant,
however,
contended
during
the
evidence
that
in
the
instant
case,
a
special
price
was
involved
because
of
the
application
of
the
theory
of
a
special
purchaser,
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada.
The
special
price
for
the
V-Day
value
was
$419,000.
3.07.1
The
appellant’s
appraiser,
Mr
Keenleyside,
contended
that
a
bank,
as
a
purchaser
of
this
class,
was
ready
to
pay
70%
more
than
a
normal
investor
or
user
for
the
subject
property.
This
figure
is
based
on
five
purchases
made
from
1963
to
1973
by
the
following
types
of
purchasers:
bank,
company,
motel,
shopping
centre
and
gas
station,
located
in
the
districts
of
Victoria,
Burnaby
and
Port
Coquitlam.
Applying
the
rate
of
1.70%
to
the
figure
of
$246,500,
at
which
he
arrived
for
the
normal
price
in
his
report,
he
concluded
that
$419,000
was
the
value
on
December
31,
1971
(1.70%
X
$246,500).
3.07.2
The
appellant’s
appraiser,
Mr
Keenleyside,
confined
the
figure
of
1.70%
above
in
showing
that
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada
paid,
in
1976,
$820,562
($825,000
-
$4,438
of
equipment)
for
the
subject
property
(lots
1,
10,
12,
13,
14
and
buildings)
which
had
a
normal
value
of
$462,000.
This
gives
a
rate
of
1.77%.
If
one
considers
that
after
the
purchase,
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada
sold
lot
10
for
$44,000
and
demolished
the
buildings
on
lots
12
and
13
which
had
a
value
of
$59,332
in
1976,
this
means
that
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada
paid
in
fact
$776,562
($820,562
-
$44,000).
This
is
1.8578
times
its
value
to
a
normal
investor
who
would
have
paid
$418,000
($462,000
-
$44,000).
3.07.3
The
main
reasons
given
in
the
report
by
Mr
Keenleyside
(Exhibit
A-2)
to
base
his
conclusions
are
cited:
Summary
and
Final
Conclusions
The
question
of
definition
of
market
value
is
the
major
issue
in
cases
where
there
is
a
property
of
special
utility
to
a
particular
purchaser.
To
analyze
this
situation
a
longer
more
detailed
definition
of
market
value
is
considered.
This
one
is
from
the
American
Institute
of
Real
Estate
Appraisers
Terminology
Hand
book,
4th
Edition.
“Market
Value
—
The
highest
price
in
terms
of
money
which
a
property
will
bring
in
a
competitive
and
open
market
under
all
conditions
requisite
to
a
fair
sale,
the
buyer
and
seller,
each
acting
prudently,
knowledgeably
and
assuming
the
price
is
not
affected
by
undue
stimulus.
Implicit
in
this
definition
is
the
consummation
of
a
sale
as
of
a
specified
date
and
the
passing
of
title
from
seller
to
buyer
under
conditions
thereby:
1.
buyer
and
seller
are
typically
motivated.
2.
both
parties
are
well
informed
or
well
advised,
and
each
acting
in
what
he
considers
his
own
best
interest.
3.
A
reasonable
time
is
allowed
for
exposure
in
the
open
market.
4.
payment
is
made
in
cash
or
its
equivalent.
5.
financing,
if
any,
is
on
terms
generally
available
in
in
the
community
at
the
specified
date
and
typical
for
the
property
type
in
its
locale.
6.
the
price
represents
a
normal
consideration
for
the
property
sold
unaffected
by
special
financing
amounts
and/or
terms,
services,
fees,
costs,
or
credit
incurred
in
the
transaction.
Numerous
definitions
of
Market
Value
have
been
devised
over
the
years
by
professional
organizations,
government
bodies,
courts,
etcetera.
The
Supreme
Courts
of
most
states
have
handed
down
definitions
of
Market
Value
for
use
in
the
state
courts.
These
definitions
are
subject
to
frequent
change.
Persons
performing
appraisal
services
which
may
be
subject
to
litigation
are
cautioned
to
seek
the
exact
definition
of
Market
Value
in
the
jurisdiction
in
which
the
services
are
being
performed.
It,
in
general,
says
the
same
thing
as
the
one
shown
earlier.
To
me,
item
2,
in
the
explanation
is
all
important.
“2.
both
parties
are
well
informed
or
well
advised,
and
each
acting
in
what
he
considers
his
own
best
interest.”
The
vendor
knew
what
he
wanted
for
the
property
considering
his
future
plans
for
the
four
lots.
The
purchaser,
I
would
accept
as
being
well
informed.
I
understand
they
had
it
appraised.
They
didn't
have
to
buy
it.
They
could
have
moved
to
the
Mall
when
it
was
built
and
subleased
their
space
for
the
rest
of
the
lease.
It
seems
to
me
another
bank,
a
credit
union
or
trust
company
would
have
picked
it
up.
The
other
question
is,
did
the
same
motivations
exist
in
1971
as
they
did
in
1976?
The
Royal
Bank
moved
to
this
site
in
1955
in
2,520
sq
ft.
In
1973
the
bank
required
further
expansion
and
was
suggesting
about
8,000
sq
ft
as
their
requirement.
In
1971
they
had
been
on
this
site
for
16
years.
In
1976
—
21
years.
In
1971,
the
neighbourhood
was
moving
and
taking
all
things
into
consideration,
it
seems
to
me
that
all
of
the
ingredients
that
motivated
them
in
1976
were
present
in
1971
and
that
they
would
have
acted
in
a
similar
manner.
In
conclusion,
the
following
table
sets
out
my
views.
|
1971
Value
|
1976
Value
|
Lot
14
|
$343,400
|
$486,744
|
Lot
13
|
75,650
|
131,904
|
Lot
12
|
—
|
157,914
|
Lot
10
|
—
|
44,000
|
|
$820,562
|
3.08
The
basic
figures
of
this
computation
were,
in
fact,
confirmed
by
the
respondent’s
witness,
Mr
Innes
James
Mitchell,
leasing
officer
of
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada
who
has
been
employed
with
the
said
bank
for
twenty-nine
years.
According
to
that
witness,
in
1976
the
appraisal
by
a
firm
of
independent
appraisers
in
the
Duncan
area,
Whitham
&
Company,
showed
that
the
subject
property
had
a
fair
market
value
of
$460,000
($414,000
for
the
land).
The
bank
paid
$825,000.
3.09
The
respondent’s
appraiser
did
not
deny
the
existence
of
the
theory
of
the
special
purchasers,
but
said
it
was
not
applicable
in
the
present
case
in
1971.
The
Royal
Bank
of
Canada
indeed
in
1971
had
no
special
interest
in
purchasing
the
property.
This
fact
was
confirmed
by
Mr
Mitchell
of
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada.
The
latter,
however,
said
that
in
1971,
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada
could
foresee
an
expansion
in
the
future,
but
the
bank
was
not
interested
in
buying
the
property
in
1971.
The
bank
had
28
employees,
and
still
had
room
for
5
or
6
more.
In
fact,
they
were
overcrowded
in
1976
when
the
number
of
employees
reached
36.
3.10
Mr
Mitchell,
however,
admitted
that
the
rent
the
bank
paid
in
1971
was
considerably
“more
than
the
going
rate
for
property
in
Duncan
at
that
time”
and
that
“this
particular
location
was
a
special
value
to
the
Bank”.
In
fact,
the
bank
paid
$5.65
per
square
foot.
3.11
Pursuant
to
the
appraisal
of
Mr
Jones,
(Exhibit
R-4
at
page
26)
one
of
the
respondent’s
appraisers,
the
normal
rental
rate
in
the
area
in
1971
was
$3.80
per
square
foot.
3.12
Mr
Jones,
on
the
income
approach,
used
the
capitalization
rate
of
9%
in
computing
the
V-Day
value
and
5%
for
the
1976
value.
At
the
rate
of
9%,
the
1976
value
would
be
$390,000.
The
property
was
sold
for
$825,000.
Mr
Jones
admitted
in
cross-examination
that
the
application
of
the
5%
rate
in
1971
would
give
a
V-Day
value
of
about
$460,000.
3.13
Mr
Pyne,
a
town
planner
and
urbanist
of
the
City
of
Duncan,
confirmed
the
testimony
of
Mr
Keenleyside,
the
appellant’s
appraiser,
by
saying
that
in
1971
the
establishment
in
Duncan
was
there,
the
basic
development
had
really
all
taken
place
and
that
Duncan
had
already
established
its
pattern
of
growth.
3.14
Also,
there
was
a
problem
concerning
the
recapture
of
depreciation
and
the
parties
did
not
give
evidence
on
this
point,
following
an
agreement
to
the
effect
that
first
they
would
wait
for
the
decision
to
be
given
by
the
Board
on
the
V-Day
value.
After
that
decision
if
no
settlement
was
reached
between
the
parties
concerning
the
recapture,
they
would
come
back
before
the
Board.
4.
Law
—
Cases
at
Law
—
Analysis
4.01
Law
The
main
provisions
involved
in
the
present
case
are
sections
3,
38,
39,
40
and
53
of
the
Income
Tax
Act
and
sections
20
and
26
of
the
Income
Tax
Application
Rules.
They
shall
be
quoted
in
the
Analysis,
if
necessary.
4.02
Cases
at
Law
and
Doctrine
The
counsel
for
both
parties
referred
to
the
following
cases
at
law
and
doctrine:
A.
Cases
at
Law
1.
William
Earl
Laycock
v
The
Queen,
[1978]
CTC
471;
78
DTC
6349;
2.
Wilfred
Riendeau
v
MNR,
[1982]
CTC
2433;
82
DTC
1412;
3.
Demco
Management
Ltd
v
MNR,
[1982]
CTC
2283;
82
DTC
1248;
4.
Dr
Lloyd
Miller
v
MNR,
[1978]
CTC
2924;
78
DTC
1666;
5.
Bay
Centre
Apartments
Ltd
v
MNR,
[1981]
CTC
2521;
81
DTC
489;
6.
Henry
and
G
wen
ni
th
Appell
v
MNR,
[1981]
CTC
2232;
81
DTC
206;
7.
Les
Meubles
de
Maskinongé
Inc
et
al
v
MNR,
[1979]
CTC
2028;
79
DTC
66;
8.
Dubbel
Wear
Holdings
Ltd
v
MNR,
[1981]
CTC
2348;
81
DTC
351;
9.
Fambau
Limited
v
MNR,
[1982]
CTC
2228;
82
DTC
1027;
10.
Estate
of
A
M
Collings
Henderson
v
MNR,
[1973]
CTC
636;
73
DTC
5471;
11.
The
Queen
v
National
System
of
Baking
of
Alberta
Limited,
[1978]
CTC
30;
78
DTC
6018;
[1980]
CTC
237;
80
DTC
6178;
12.
Stanley
M
Smith
et
al
v
MNR,
[1980]
CTC
2208;
80
DTC
1185;
13.
Untermeyer
v
A-G
BC,
[1929]
1
DLR
315;
B.
Doctrine
14.
J
G
Vicq,
Farm
Property
Valuation
in
the
Prairie
Provinces,
an
article
in
the
“Canadian
Tax
Journal’’,
Vol
25,
No
6
—
November/December
1977;
15.
Richard
M
Wise,
Valuation
and
the
Income
Tax
Act,
an
article
in
the
“Canadian
Tax
Journal”,
Vol
29,
No
5
—
September/October
1981;
16.
lan
R
Campbell,
Canada
Valuation
Service,
pages
4-11
to
4-35;
17.
Robert
W
Winstead,
Real
Estate
Appraisal
Desk
Book,
“Techniques
in
Selecting
Capitalization
Rates”,
Prentice-Hall,
Inc,
Englewood
Cliffs,
NJ
1968;
18.
Introduction
to
Real
Estate
Appraising,
Published
by
the
Appraisal
Institute
of
Canada,
1977
edition
revised
1980,
“The
Comparative
Method”
at
pages
12-20
and
12-21;
19.
Alfred
A
Ring,
The
Valuation
of
Real
Estate,
Second
Edition
—
1970,
Prentice-Hall,
Inc,
Englewood
Cliffs,
New
Jersey,
“Determining
the
Rate
of
Capitalization”
at
pages
238
to
243;
20.
Ian
R
Campbell,
Business
Valuation:
Some
Current
Thoughts,
an
article
in
the
“Canadian
Tax
Journal”,
Vol
23,
No
4,
pages
373
ss.
4.03
Analysis
4.03.1
The
first
point
is
whether
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada
was
a
special
purchaser
in
the
instant
case.
lan
R
Campbell
defines
“special
purchasers”
in
his
article
in
the
Canadian
Tax
Journal
(referred
to
above
in
para
4.02(20):
Special
purchasers
may
be
defined
as
those
who,
for
one
or
more
reasons,
are
williing
to
pay
a
higher
price
for
a
given
asset
than
are
other
purchasers.
In
a
similar
manner,
special
purchasers
of
businesses
generally
pay
higher
prices
than
do
more
ordinary
purchasers;
however,
their
motivations
are
related
to
economics
as
opposed
to
sentiment.
The
premiums
paid
by
such
purchasers
stem
from
their
ability
to
realize
greater
earnings
through
combination
of
the
acquired
and
their
own
operation
than
the
two
businesses
could
generate
separately
and/or
to
the
reduced
risk
experienced
by
such
a
purchaser
following
acquisition
(operating
and/or
financial
“synergies”).
In
general
terms,
the
following
may
be
cited
as
major
factors
potentially
influencing
the
level
of
operating
and
financial
synergies
to
be
realized
on
a
post
acquisition
basis
and
thus
influencing
the
quantum
of
a
special
purchaser
premium:
(a)
the
ability
to
horizontally
integrate
the
purchasing
and
acquired
companies;
that
is,
the
ability
to
consolidate
the
managements,
sales,
and
production
functions
of
two
like
entities.
For
example,
the
purchase
of
one
steel
company
by
another
steel
company;
(b)
a
reduction
in
the
dispersion
of
cash
flows
ie,
anticyclical
diversification.
For
example,
the
purchase
of
a
company
producing
snowmobiles
by
a
company
producing
boats
and
motors;
(c)
a
reduction
of
input
and
output
risk
as
a
result
of
obtaining
secured
inputs
and/or
a
locked-in
market
for
outputs
ie,
vertical
integration.
For
example,
the
purchase
of
a
rubber
plantation
by
a
tire
manufacturer;
and,
(d)
a
reduction
in
the
cost
of
financing
operations;
that
is,
a
reduction
in
the
purchaser’s
cost
of
capital.
For
example,
the
purchase
of
a
company
with
a
substantial
tax
loss
carry
forward
which
can
be
utilized
by
the
acquiring
entity
in
lieu
of
likely
more
costly
forms
of
financing
in
the
future.
Numerous
cases
illustrating
the
existence
of
special
purchasers
could
be
cited.
For
example,
when
recently
assessing
a
possible
acquisition
candidate
a
prospective
purchaser
found,
much
to
his
surprise,
that
the
candidate,
which
was
currently
generating
approximately
$15,000
in
after-tax
income
per
year,
could,
if
acquired
by
the
prospective
purchaser,
generate
$75,000
per
year
on
the
same
sales
vol-
urne.
This
resulted
from
the
fact
that
the
purchasers
and
vendors
businesses
were
almost
exactly
aligned,
and
with
the
exception
of
sales
commissions,
all
indirect
expenses
of
the
vendor
could
be
eliminated
by
the
purchaser
following
acquisition.
At
the
same
time,however,
the
prospective
purchaser
also
realized
that
there
were
several
other
possible
purchasers
who
could
similarly
realize
substantial
operating
synergies.
Accordingly,
the
prospective
purchaser
hastily
offered
the
vendor
7
times
current
earnings
or
$105,000.
Without
realizing
the
concept
of,
or
the
possible
existence
of,
special
purchasers,
the
vendor
accepted
the
offer.
In
effect,
the
transaction
was
consummated
at
1.4
times
post-acquisition
earnings.
Although
such
extreme
cases
may
be
rare,
at
least
two
conclusions
can
be
drawn
from
this
example.
First,
only
when
comparable
transactions
are
recognized
as
such
through
first
hand
knowledge
(by
being
party
to,
or
an
advisor
to
parties
to
such
transactions)
is
it
appropriate
to
treat
such
transactions
as
comparables
in
determining
fair
market
value
in
the
notional
marketplace?
An
outsider
looking
at
the
final
transaction
might
reason
that
the
purchaser
paid
7
times
after-tax
earnings
for
the
acquired
business
when,
in
effect,
the
purchaser
paid
only
1.4
times
post-acquisition
earnings.
Second,
anyone
who
proposes
to
sell
a
business
in
the
open
market
should
carefully
review
the
marketplace
for
possible
special
purchasers
and
attempt
to
determine
the
quantum
of
those
synergistic
benefits
that
such
purchasers
might
derive.
In
the
above-cited
example,
had
the
vendor
recognized
the
special
purchaser
concept
and
realized
its
applicability
in
the
sale
of
his
company,
it
is
probable
that
he
could
have
induced
a
bidding
situation
between
special
purchasers
and
garnered
a
substantially
higher
price
than
was
in
fact
realized.
4.03.2
The
application
of
this
principle
can
be
applied
in
different
ways.
The
courts
have
already
applied
the
principle
of
the
special
purchaser
in
the
Laycock,
(Supra),
case
where
Mr
Justice
Smith
(FCTD)
accepted
that
a
piece
of
land
of
119
acres
had
a
value
of
$135
per
acre
in
1971
as
ordinary
farmland,
as
contended
by
the
Minister
but,
however,
increased
this
value
by
50%
to
take
into
account
the
fact
that
the
taxpayer’s
land
was
a
logical
site
if
C
Ltd
should
decide
to
expand.
In
fact,
C
Ltd
in
1971
offered
$400
per
acre
for
40
acres
only.
In
1973,
the
whole
piece
of
land
of
159
acres
was
acquired
by
C
Ltd
for
$300
per
acre.
Mr
Justice
Smith
then
decided
that
the
V-Day
value
was
$400
per
acre,
for
the
first
40
acres,
and
$202.50
for
the
remaining
119
acres
as
explained
above.
In
Les
Meubles
de
Maskinongé
Inc
et
al,
(supra),
the
Tax
Review
Board
accepted
in
part
the
Minister’s
thesis
based
on
the
theory
of
the
special
purchaser.
The
value
of
the
shares
of
the
said
company
was
fixed
at
$195,000
despite
the
fact
that
the
said
company
was
in
bankruptcy
when
the
shares
were
bought
by
Les
Associés
Houde
Inc
for
$1.
Some
of
the
reasons
for
applying
the
theory
of
the
special
purchaser
were
that
the
purchaser,
Les
Associes
Houde
Inc,
was
in
the
same
kind
of
business
as
Les
Meubles
de
Maskinongé
Inc,
the
latter
had
200
qualified
employees
and
still
had
an
important
list
of
clients.
Moreover,
the
buildings
and
equipment
had
a
good
value.
The
amount
of
$225,000
paid
to
Dr
Bernèche,
the
former
main
shareholder
of
Les
meubles
de
Maskinongé
inc
as
special
consultant
($15,000
for
15
years)
was
considered
by
the
Tax
Review
Board
in
part
as
salary
($30,000)
and
in
part
as
payment
of
the
shares
($195,000).
4.03.3
In
the
instant
case,
the
preponderance
of
the
evidence
is
to
the
effect
that
in
1976
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada
was
a
special
purchaser.
The
testimony
of
the
appellant’s
appraiser
is
that
the
normal
value
of
the
property
was
$462,000,
but
$820,562
was
paid
(para
3.07.2).
The
said
normal
value
was
confirmed
by
the
respondent’s
witness,
Mr
Mitchell,
employee
of
the
purchaser
for
29
years,
who
said
that
the
Royal
Bank
of
Canada,
before
purchasing
the
property,
paid
an
independent
appraiser
to
value
it.
The
valuation
was
$460,000
(para
3.08).
4.03.4
Did
the
same
special
value
exist
in
1971?
The
uncontradicted
adduced
evidence
and
the
facts
described
in
paragraphs
3.07.1,
3.07.3,
3.09
and
3.10
convinced
the
Board
of
the
existence
of
the
special
value
in
1971.
Moreover,
some
conclusions
of
Mr
Jones,
one
of
the
respondent’s
appraisers,
confirmed
the
appellant’s
thesis
(see
paras
3.11
and
3.12).
4.03.5
Is
it
correct
to
compute
the
special
value
by
taking
the
rate
of
1.70%
of
the
normal
value?
The
preponderance
of
evidence
is
to
the
effect
that
the
Board
must
accept
1.70%
and
the
figure
of
$419,000
as
the
spécial
value
at
V-Day.
4.03.6
Concerning
the
recapture
of
depreciation,
the
Board
will
wait
for
the
agreement
of
the
parties
(para
3.14).
5.
Conclusion
The
appeal
is
allowed
in
part
and
the
matter
referred
back
to
the
respondent
for
reassessment
in
accordance
with
the
above
reasons
for
judgment.
Appeal
allowed.