Teskey,
T.C.C.J.:—
The
appellant
elected
to
have
his
appeal
against
an
assessment
for
1989
heard
pursuant
to
the
informal
procedure.
Issue
The
Minister
of
National
Revenue
(the
Minister"),
in
making
his
assessment,
restricted
the
appellant’s
farming
loss
by
applying
subsection
31(1)
of
the
Income
Tax
Act
(the
"Act").
The
appellant
claims
that
he
is
a
class
1
farmer,
as
defined
by
Dickson,
J.
as
he
then
was,
in
Moldowan
v.
The
Queen,
[1978]
1
S.C.R.
480,
[1977]
C.T.C.
310,
77
D.T.C.
5213
and
therefore
subsection
31(1)
of
the
Act
should
not
be
applied.
Facts
The
appellant,
a
commerce
graduate,
has
a
full-time
job
with
a
firm
of
insurance
brokers
in
Calgary
as
its
financial
manager.
This
is
basically
a
nine
to
five,
five
days
a
week
job.
The
year
end
creates
a
little
overtime
work
which
is
insignificant.
Prior
to
1989,
he
farmed
as
a
breeder
and
racer
of
standardbred
horses.
By
year
end
of
1988,
he
had
suffered
losses
on
this
total
operation
for
three
straight
years.
He
realized
that,
of
his
total
loss
for
1987
of
$9,252,
only
$715
of
this
loss
was
attributable
to
his
racing
portion
of
the
operation.
The
appellant
claims
that
in
1988,
even
though
the
total
operation
had
a
loss
of
$7,960,
the
race
portion
had
a
profit
of
$4,050.
With
this
knowledge,
he
decided
to
abandon
his
breeding
operation
and
only
be
in
a
racing
operation.
On
January
1,
1989,
he
owned
three
horses,
namely,
a
ten-year-old
brood
mare,
called
Show
Baby,
which
his
brother
kept
at
no
expense
to
the
appellant.
Show
Baby
had
not
been
bred
in
1988
and
was
not
to
be
bred
again.
The
other
two
horses
were
offsprings
of
Show
Baby
called
Royal
Occasion
("Royal")
and
Regal
Rampage
("Regal").
Royal
was
a
four-year-old
and
Regal
was
a
three-year-old.
Neither
Royal
nor
Regal
earned
any
money
in
1989.
Royal
had
to
be
put
down
and
Regal
was
given
away
rather
than
being
sold
to
a
packing
plant
for
$200.
In
November
of
1989,
the
appellant
purchased
two
horses
in
Kentucky
namely
Sugar
Kyle
("Kyle")
and
Timeless
Almhurst
("Timeless").
Kyle,
a
two-
year-old
colt
was
purchased
for
U.S.
$16,000.
Timeless,
a
yearling
filly
was
purchased
for
U.S.
$2,500.
Kyle
in
1990
had
four
starts
which
resulted
in
one
win,
two
second
places
and
one
third
place.
The
colt
then
came
down
with
a
virus
and
had
to
be
pastured
until
June
of
1989.
In
September,
he
started
racing
again
but
his
times
were
not
competitive.
Kyle
was
kept
until
March
of
1991
when
he
was
sold
for
$600.
Timeless
also
started
to
race
in
1990
and
had
a
win
and
a
second
place
when
she
developed
a
physical
problem
which
could
not
be
overcome
and
her
racing
career,
for
all
intents
and
purposes,
ended
in
the
spring
of
1990
and
although
she
was
put
on
lease
in
1991,
she
was
eventually
sold
in
1992
for
$700.
The
appellant
claimed
that
his
plan
was
to
purchase
two
horses
a
year
in
Kentucky
for
$20,000
and
import
them
to
Alberta.
By
1991,
this
operation
would
produce
a
profit
of
$2,000
and
by
1993
a
gross
profit
of
$30,000.
The
appellant
gave
evidence
to
the
effect
that
out
of
400
horses
bred
for
racing
the
following
results
on
average
would
occur:
100
would
never
reach
the
race
track.
100
would
be
marginal
with
no
profit.
100
would
be
slightly
profitable
taking
into
consideration
winnings
and
sale
price
at
end
of
a
racing
career.
Of
the
remaining
100,
two
would
be
exceptional
and
would
produce
huge
winnings
and
the
other
98
would
double
in
value.
The
appellant's
only
assets
were
his
horses
and
he
had
no
plans
to
invest
in
any
other
capital
assets.
All
animals
would
be
boarded
at
the
tracks.
His
time
spent
in
this
racing
enterprise
did
not
nearly
match
his
employment
time.
Danny
Dayril
Garinger
("Garinger")
the
executive
director
of
the
Alberta
Standard
Breeders
Association
was
called
by
the
appellant
to
give
evidence.
He
said
that
in
his
opinion
to
be
successful
in
a
standardbred
racing
enterprise
the
owner
had
to
have:
1.
adequate
research.
2.
contacts
with
successful
people.
3.
knowledge
of
the
rules.
4.
high
credibility.
5.
luck.
6.
awareness
of
the
business
and
understanding
of
the
general
aspects
thereof
(this
would
include
sufficient
capital
to
carry
a
losing
enterprise
from
the
required
start-up
period).
With
regards
to
“luck”
he
compared
the
purchasing
of
race
hoses
to
the
hockey
draft.
There
was
a
great
deal
of
luck
in
the
draft
as
well
as
in
the
selection
of
horses
to
be
purchased
at
auctions.
However,
if
a
horse
doesn't
win
or
place,
there
is
no
income,
whereas
hockey
attracts
spectators
whether
the
team
wins
or
loses.
He
said
that
in
1989,
there
were
approximately
1,000
horses
racing
in
Alberta
for
prizes
totalling
10
million
dollars.
The
average
racer
in
Alberta
earns
annually
as
much
as
its
cost
for
upkeep
and
that
20
per
cent
of
the
racers
earns
80
per
cent
of
the
prize
money.
He
said
in
review
of
the
breeding
of
both
Kyle
and
Timeless
that
without
seeing
either
horse
that
they
appeared
to
have
a
better
than
average
potential.
This
opinion
is
worthless
and
does
not
assist
the
appellant
in
any
way.
In
1990,
the
appellant,
even
though
he
claims
he
had
the
funds
to
do
so,
did
not
purchase
any
more
race
horses
and
abandoned
the
enterprise.
He
claims
that
he
started
on
this
route
because
of
a
special
relationship
he
had
with
a
particular
trainer.
This
relationship
deteriorated
in
1990
and
was
a
major
factor
in
his
decision
to
abandon
his
race
horse
operation.
Legal
principles
The
premier
decision
is
Moldowan,
in
which
Dickson,
J.,
as
he
then
was,
said
at
pages
485-86
(C.T.C.
313-14;
D.T.C.
5215):
There
is
a
vast
case
literature
on
what
reasonable
expectation
of
profit
means
and
it
is
by
no
means
entirely
consistent.
In
my
view,
whether
a
taxpayer
has
a
reasonable
expectation
of
profit
is
an
objective
determination
to
be
made
from
all
of
the
facts.
The
following
criteria
should
be
considered:
the
profit
and
loss
experience
in
past
years,
the
taxpayer's
training,
the
taxpayer's
intended
course
of
action,
the
capability
of
the
venture
as
capitalized
to
show
a
profit
after
charging
capital
cost
allowance.
He
went
on
to
say
at
pages
487-88
(C.T.C.
315,
D.T.C.
5216):
In
my
opinion,
the
Income
Tax
Act
as
a
whole
envisages
three
classes
of
farmers:
(1)
a
taxpayer,
for
whom
farming
may
reasonably
be
expected
to
provide
the
bulk
of
income
or
the
centre
of
work
routine.
Such
a
taxpayer,
who
looks
to
farming
for
his
livelihood,
is
free
of
the
limitation
of
subsection
13(1)
in
those
years
in
which
he
sustains
a
farming
loss.
(2)
the
taxpayer
who
does
not
look
to
farming,
or
to
farming
and
some
subordinate
source
of
income,
for
his
livelihood
but
carried
on
farming
as
a
sideline
business.
Such
a
taxpayer
is
entitled
to
the
deductions
spelled
out
in
subsection
13(1)
in
respect
of
farming
losses.
(3)
the
taxpayer
who
does
not
look
to
farming,
or
to
farming
and
some
subordinate
source
of
income,
for
his
livelihood
and
who
carried
on
some
farming
activities
as
a
hobby.
The
losses
sustained
by
such
a
taxpayer
on
his
non-business
farming
are
not
deductible
in
any
amount.
The
reference
in
subsection
13(1)
to
a
taxpayer
whose
source
of
income
is
a
combination
of
farming
and
some
other
source
of
income
is
a
reference
to
class
(1).
It
contemplates
a
man
whose
major
preoccupation
is
farming,
but
it
recognizes
that
such
a
man
may
have
other
pecuniary
interests
as
well,
such
as
income
from
investments,
or
income
from
a
sideline
employment
or
business.
The
section
provides
that
these
subsidiary
interests
will
not
place
the
taxpayer
in
class
(2)
and
thereby
limit
the
deductibility
of
any
loss
which
may
be
suffered
to
$5,000.
While
a
quantum
measurement
of
farming
income
is
relevant,
it
is
not
alone
decisive.
The
test
is
again
both
relative
and
objective,
and
one
may
employ
the
criteria
indicative
of
"chief
source”
to
distinguish
whether
or
not
the
interest
is
auxiliary.
A
man
who
has
farmed
all
of
his
life
does
not
become
disentitled
to
class
(1)
classification
simply
because
he
comes
into
an
inheritance.
On
the
other
hand,
a
man
who
changes
occupational
direction
and
commits
his
energies
and
capital
to
farming
as
a
main
expectation
of
income
is
not
disentitled
to
deduct
the
full
impact
of
start-up
costs.
The
Moldowan
decision
was
dealt
with
at
length
by
the
Federal
Court
of
Appeal
in
The
Queen
v.
Morrissey,
[1989]
1
C.T.C.
235,
89
D.T.C.
5080.
Mahoney,
J.
said
at
page
242
(D.T.C.
5084):
On
a
proper
application
of
the
test
propounded
in
Moldowan,
when,
as
here,
it
is
found
that
profitability
is
improbable
notwithstanding
all
the
time
and
capital
the
taxpayer
is
able
and
willing
to
devote
to
farming,
the
conclusion
based
on
the
civil
burden
of
proof
must
be
that
farming
is
not
a
chief
source
of
that
taxpayer's
income.
To
be
income
in
the
context
of
the
Income
Tax
Act
that
which
is
received
must
be
money
or
money's
worth.
Absent
actual
or
potential
profitability,
farming
cannot
be
a
chief
source
of
his
income
even
though
the
admission
that
he
was
farming
with
a
reasonable
expectation
of
profit
is
tantamount
to
an
admission
which
itself
may
not
be
borne
out
by
the
evidence,
namely,
that
it
is
at
least
a
source
of
income.
Strayer,
J.
in
Mohl
v.
The
Queen,
[1989]
1
C.T.C.
425,
89
D.T.C.
5236
after
citing
both
Moldowan
and
Morrissey
said
at
page
428
(D.T.C.
5238):
.
.
.for
a
person
to
claim
that
farming
is
a
chief
source
of
income,
he
must
show
not
only
a
substantial
commitment
to
it
in
terms
of
the
time
he
spends
and
the
capital
invested,
but
also
must
demonstrate
that
there
is
a
reasonable
expectation
of
it
being
significantly
profitable.
I
use
the
term
significantly
profitable”
because
it
appears
from
the
Morrissey
decision
that
the
quantum
of
expected
profit
cannot
be
ignored
and
I
take
this
to
mean
that
one
must
have
regard
to
the
relative
amounts
expected
to
be
earned
from
farming
and
from
other
sources.
Unless
the
amount
reasonably
expected
to
be
earned
from
farming
is
substantial
in
relation
to
other
sources
of
income
then
farming
will
at
best
be
regarded
as
a
"sideline
business”
to
which
the
restriction
on
losses
will
apply
in
accordance
with
subsection
31(1).
The
Federal
Court
of
Appeal
in
1991
reviewed
the
Moldowan
and
Morrissey
decisions
and
The
Queen
v.
Graham,
[1985]
1
C.T.C.
380,
85
D.T.C.
5256
in
Roney
v.
M.N.R.,
[1991]
1
C.T.C.
280,
91
D.T.C.
5148.
Desjardins,
J.A.
for
the
Court
said
at
page
288
(D.T.C.
5155):
Start-up
costs.
.
.cannot
be
considered
as
the
basis
for
an
alternative
ground
of
decision.
The
permissible
amount
to
be
deducted
depends
on
the
class
the
taxpayer
finds
himself
in.
Furthermore
she
stated
that
when
Dickson,
J.
said
in
Moldowan
at
page
488
(C.T.C.
315,
D.T.C.
5216):
On
the
other
hand,
a
man
who
changes
occupational
direction
and
commits
his
energies
and
capital
to
farming
as
a
main
expectation
of
income
is
not
disentitled
to
deduct
the
full
impact
of
start-up
costs.
Desjardins,
J.A.,
then
went
on
to
say,
that
Dickson,
J.
was
referring
to
a
class
1
taxpayer
(farmer).
Analysis
With
these
legal
principles
in
mind,
I
must
determine
if
the
appellant's
race
horse
farming
business
would
have,
in
a
reasonable
period
of
time
as
capitalized,
produced
sufficient
income
that
it
would
have
been
the
appellant's
chief
source
of
income
or
that
his
chief
source
of
income
would
be
a
combination
of
farming
and
his
regular
employment
income,
particularly
in
light
of
Strayer,
J.'s
Mohl
decision
that
the
farming
operation
must
be
"significantly
profitable".
The
appellant
has
failed
to
convince
me
that
his
business
plan
was
a
sound
business
adventure.
His
business
plan,
as
produced
in
Exhibit
A-13,
is
not
realistic.
It
does
not
take
into
consideration
many
factors
such
as
veterinary
fees
which
undoubtedly
could
be
substantial.
It
is
also
based
on
the
assumption
that,
in
1993
the
two
five-year-olds
would
only
lose
$5,000;
the
two
four-year-olds
would
together
earn
$10,000;
the
two
three-year-olds
would
together
earn
$25,000
and
the
one
two-year-old
would
only
lose
$6,000,
thus
producing
a
profit
of
$24,000
on
racing
only.
This
does
not
take
into
consideration
the
sale
of
two
horses
at
$18,000.
Against
this,
I
must
look
at
his
actual
history
and
compare
it
against
the
percentages
as
given
by
Garinger.
The
two
horses
the
appellant
had
in
January
of
1989
never
earned
any
money.
The
two
horses
purchased
in
Kentucky
in
November
of
1989
were
total
losses
both
as
to
the
winnings
and
the
sale.
The
enterprise
was
partially
based
on
the
ability
of
an
outside
person
namely,
the
trainer.
This
is
not
a
sound
business
foundation.
The
plan
did
not
take
into
consideration
luck
nor
the
percentages
as
given
by
Garinger.
Luck
can
be
either
good
or
bad.
For
every
horse
that
does
exceptionally
well,
there
are
50
that
never
reach
the
track,
50
that
race
and
lose
money,
50
that
race
and
break
even
and
49
that
do
better.
Even
if
the
appellant,
with
his
knowledge,
could
eliminate
buying
horses
that
never
race,
the
odds
were
that
only
one
in
three
would
make
money.
The
appellant
has
failed
to
convince
me
that
his
racing
of
standardbred
horses
as
planned
would
produce
in
five
years
“significant
profit".
Even
if
I
accepted
his
five-year
plan
(E.A.B.)
which
I
specifically
reject,
it
fails
to
demonstrate
“
significant
profit”
and
to
fit
the
definition
of
a
class
1
farmer.
There
is
nothing
before
me
to
suggest
that
the
appellant's
horses
would
do
any
different
than
average.
In
fact,
his
history
would
suggest
a
below
average
performance.
The
adventure
was
speculative.
Without
winnings
in
excess
of
upkeep
to
either
pay
back
the
purchase
price
or
to
maintain
a
sale
price,
the
operation
would
be
a
losing
proposition.
The
appellant
was
chasing
a
dream,
it
being
highly
probable
that
he
would
never
have
turned
a
profit.
Based
on
the
evidence
before
me
and
for
these
reasons,
the
appeal
is
dismissed.
If
the
Minister
had
disallowed
all
losses,
I
would
still
have
dismissed
the
appeal.
This
was
a
highly
speculative
adventure
with
very
little
chance,
if
any,
of
producing
a
profit
in
the
future.
In
1989
he
had
no
chance
of
making
a
profit.
The
losses
cannot
even
be
classified
as
start-up
costs.
Start-up
losses
can
only
be
used
if
the
enterprise,
as
existing,
can
be
shown
to
produce,
in
a
reasonable
length
of
time,
substantial
profit.
I
would
classify
the
appellant
as
a
class
3
farmer.
Appeal
dismissed.